Revision as of 18:25, 14 August 2008 edit65.246.126.130 (talk) →Child labor laws← Previous edit | Latest revision as of 04:29, 20 August 2024 edit undoBD2412 (talk | contribs)Autopatrolled, IP block exemptions, Administrators2,458,063 editsm →Other applications: clean up Washington, D.C. punctuation issues, replaced: Washington, D.C | → Washington, D.C. |Tag: AWB | ||
(209 intermediate revisions by more than 100 users not shown) | |||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
{{Short description|Economic concept}} | |||
'''Bootleggers and Baptists''' is a ] of the origin of particular ]s first proposed by ] in a 1983 ''Regulation Magazine'' article. The story is based on an actual phenomenon in certain ], though it can easily be applied to other regulations. | |||
]n police agents dump illegal ] in 1925, ] photo courtesy Orange County Archives.]] | |||
'''Bootleggers and Baptists''' is a concept put forth by regulatory economist ],<ref name=BB>{{cite journal | last = Yandle | first = Bruce | author-link = Bruce Yandle | title = Bootleggers and Baptists: the education of a regulatory economist | journal = ] | volume = 7 | issue = 3 | pages = 12–16 | date = May–June 1983 | url = http://www.cato.org/regulation/archives }} {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160413000152/http://news.heartland.org/sites/default/files/v7n3-3.pdf |date=2016-04-13 }} | |||
==The story== | |||
:''See also'': {{cite journal | last = Yandle | first = Bruce | author-link = Bruce Yandle | title = Bootleggers and Baptists in retrospect | journal = ] | volume = 22 | issue = 3 | pages = 5–7 | date = October 1999 | url = http://www.cato.org/regulation/archives }} {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20121003182547/http://www.cato.org/pubs/regulation/regv22n3/bootleggers.pdf |date=2012-10-03 }} and {{cite book|title=Bootleggers and Baptists: How Economic Forces and Moral Persuasion Interact to Shape Regulatory Politics|date=2014|publisher=Cato Institute|isbn=978-1939709363}}</ref> derived from the observation that regulations are supported both by groups that want the ostensible purpose of the regulation, and by groups that profit from undermining that purpose.<ref>{{cite book | last = McChesney | first = Fred S. | title = Money for nothing: politicians, rent extraction, and political extortion | url = https://archive.org/details/moneyfornothingp0000mcch | url-access = registration | publisher = Harvard University Press | location = Cambridge, Massachusetts | year = 1997 | isbn = 9780674583306 }}</ref> | |||
The story begins with ]s in a rural community demanding the local government ban the sale of alcohol on Sundays. "Alcohol", they might say, "is a vile drink and efforts should be curbed to restrict its spread through society, especially on the ]'s day." Under this noble tone, the government complies and enacts a ban. | |||
For much of the 20th century, ] and other ] were prominent in political activism for ] restricting the sale of alcohol. ] sold alcohol illegally, and got more business if legal sales were restricted.<ref name=BB /> Yandle wrote that "Such a coalition makes it easier for politicians to favor both groups. ... the Baptists lower the costs of favor-seeking for the bootleggers, because politicians can pose as being motivated purely by the public interest even while they promote the interests of well-funded businesses. ... take the moral high ground, while the bootleggers persuade the politicians quietly, behind closed doors."<ref name=GW>{{cite journal | last1 = Yandle | first1 = Bruce | last2 = Buck | first2 = Stuart | author-link = Bruce Yandle | title = Bruce, bootleggers, Baptists, and the global warming battle | journal = ] | doi = 10.2139/ssrn.279914 | ssrn = 279914 | date = 14 August 2001 }}</ref> | |||
But the demand for alcohol doesn't disappear when the supply does. People still want to drink on Sundays and so the ]s step up and illegally sell alcohol. And because the supply is restricted because far few people are selling liquor, one day a week the bootlegger gains ] power and the lucrative market that goes with it. | |||
==Economic theory== | |||
Willie Morris's memoir ''North Toward Home'' example of this phenomenon: | |||
The mainstream economic theory of regulation treats politicians and administrators as brokers among interest groups.<ref>{{cite book | last1 = Baldwin | first1 = Robert | last2 = Cave | first2 = Martin | last3 = Lodge | first3 = Martin | title = The Oxford handbook of regulation | publisher = Oxford University Press | location = Oxford New York | year = 2010 | isbn = 9780199655885 }}</ref><ref>{{cite book | last = Lasswell | first = Harold | title = Politics: who gets what, when, how? | publisher = McGraw-Hill | location = New York | year = 1950 | orig-year = 1936 | oclc = 21939663 }}</ref> Bootleggers and Baptists is a specific idea in the subfield of regulatory economics that attempts to predict which interest groups will succeed in obtaining rules they favor. It holds that coalitions of opposing interests that can agree on a common rule will be more successful than one-sided groups.<ref>{{cite book | last = Kahn | first = Alfred E. | title = The economics of regulation : principles and institutions | publisher = MIT Press | location = Cambridge, Massachusetts | year = 1988 | isbn = 9780262610520 }}</ref> | |||
Baptists do not merely agitate for legislation, they help monitor and enforce it (a law against Sunday alcohol sales without significant public support would likely be ignored, or be evaded through bribery of enforcement officers). Thus bootleggers and Baptists is not just an academic restatement of the common political accusation that shadowy for-profit interests are hiding behind public-interest groups to fund deceptive legislation. It is a ] theory<ref>{{cite book | last = Bryner | first = Gary | title = Bureaucratic discretion: law and policy in federal regulatory agencies | url = https://archive.org/details/bureaucraticdisc0000bryn | url-access = registration | publisher = Pergamon Press | location = New York | year = 1987 | isbn = 9780080344935 }}</ref> to explain relative success among types of coalitions.<ref name=BB /><ref>{{citation | last = Tullock | first = Gordon | contribution = Rent seeking as a negative sum game | editor-last1 = Buchanan | editor-first1 = James M. | editor-last2 = Tollison | editor-first2 = Robert D. | editor-last3 = Tullock | editor-first3 = Gordon | title = Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society | pages = 16–38 | publisher = Texas A & M University | location = College Station | year = 1980 | isbn = 9780890960905 | postscript = .}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal | last = Wagner | first = Richard E. | title = Reviewed work: ''The Logic of Collective Action'' by Mancur Olson, Jr. | journal = ] | volume = 1 | pages = 161–170 | date = December 1966 | jstor = 25122288 }}</ref> | |||
⚫ | |||
Another part of the theory is that bootleggers and Baptists produce suboptimal legislation.<ref>{{citation | last = Buchanan | first = James M. | contribution = Rent seeking and profit seeking | editor-last1 = Buchanan | editor-first1 = James M. | editor-last2 = Tollison | editor-first2 = Robert D. | editor-last3 = Tullock | editor-first3 = Gordon | title = Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society | pages = 3–15 | publisher = Texas A & M University | location = College Station | year = 1980 | isbn = 9780890960905 | postscript = .}}</ref> Although both groups are satisfied with the outcome, broader society would be better off either with no legislation or different legislation.<ref>{{cite journal | last = Sutter | first = Daniel | title = The democratic efficiency debate and definitions of political equilibrium | journal = The Review of Austrian Economics| volume = 15 | issue = 2 | pages = 199–209 | doi = 10.1023/A:1015766621802 | date = June 2002 | s2cid = 73557743 }}</ref> For example, a surtax on Sunday alcohol sales could reduce Sunday alcohol consumption as much as making it illegal. Instead of enriching bootleggers and imposing policing costs, the surtax could raise money to be spent on, say, property tax exemptions for churches and alcoholism treatment programs. Moreover, such a program could be balanced to reflect the religious beliefs and drinking habits of everyone, not just certain groups. From the religious point of the view, the bootleggers have not been cut out of the deal, the government has become the bootlegger.<ref name=GW /> | |||
⚫ | Every so often there would be a vote to determine whether liquor should be made legal. Then, for weeks before, the town would be filled with feverish campaign activity. People would quote the old saying, "As long as the people of Mississippi can stagger to the polls, they'll vote dry." A handful of people would come right and say that liquor should be made legal, so that the bootleggers and the sheriffs would not be able to make all the money, and because the state legislature's "black-market tax" on whiskey, a pittance of a tax that actually contradicted the state constitution, was a shameful deceit. But these voices were few, and most of the campaigning was done by the preachers and the church groups. In their sermons the preachers would talk about the dangers of alcoholism, and the shame of all the liquor ads along the highways in Tennessee and Louisiana, and the temptations this offered the young people. Two or three weeks before the vote, the churches would hand out bumper stickers to put on cars; in big red letters they said, "For the sake of my family, vote dry." An older boy, the son of one of the most prosperous bootleggers, drove around town in a new Buick, with three of those bumper stickers plastered on front and back: "For the sake of my family, vote dry." |
||
Although the bootleggers and Baptists story has become a standard idea in regulatory economics,<ref>{{cite journal | last1 = Schneider | first1 = Mark | last2 = Teske | first2 = Paul | title = Toward a theory of the political entrepreneur: evidence from local government | journal = ] | volume = 86 | issue = 3 | pages = 737–747 | doi = 10.2307/1964135 | jstor = 1964135 | date = September 1992 | s2cid = 155041917 }}</ref> it has not been systematically validated as an empirical proposition. It is a catch-phrase useful in analyzing regulatory coalitions rather than an accepted principle of economics.<ref>{{cite book | last = Breyer | first = Stephen | title = Regulation and its reform | url = https://archive.org/details/regulationitsref00brey | url-access = registration | publisher = Harvard University Press | location = Cambridge, Massachusetts | year = 1982 | isbn = 9780674753761 }}</ref> | |||
==Analysis== | |||
] | |||
The bootleggers and the Baptists both have an incentive to limit the consumption of alcohol, the former with the economic reason and the latter with the ethical justification that people will support, though by their very nature the two groups wouldn't get along. The ] effectively acts as the , taking the bootlegger's campaign contributions and citing the Baptist's morals in speeches. The result can be ultimately less regulation and a certain ] with regard to alcohol consumption in the ]. Open container laws are an example. They tend to be looser in more Baptist areas.<ref></ref> | |||
⚫ | {{Reflist}} | ||
===Child labor laws=== | |||
Yandle notes that, in the 18th century, the laws against ] first appeared as a recommendation to the ] from a ] committee, which was populated in part by owners of textile mills. Unlike most mills, however, the mills the committee members owned used the latest automation technology and needed far less labor. The committee cited ethical reasons for banning child labor (more humane work force, etc.), but those mill owners on the committee knew that such a ban would hurt their competitors, who needed manual labor, far more than it would hurt them. | |||
==Literal examples== | |||
===Gambling=== | |||
An example of the regulatory ] described by this theory is the ] of the work of political ]s, ], ], ], and ], on ] ] interests for an estimated $85 million in fees. Abramoff and Scanlon grossly overbilled their clients, and all four split the multimillion-dollar take. They secretly orchestrated lobbying against their own clients in order to force them to pay for inflated lobbying services. Three lobbied legislatures while Reed remained outside, inflaming existing conservative religious sentiment against gambling in the ]. | |||
1) In 2015, liquor stores in the "]" of ] allied with local religious leaders to oppose statewide legalization of alcohol sales. Where the religious groups were opposed on moral grounds, the liquor stores were concerned over the potential loss of customers if rival stores were permitted to open in the "dry" counties of the state.<ref name="bloomberg">{{cite news | last1 = Deprez | first1 = Esmé E. | last2 = Hogue | first2 = Millie | title = Arkansas liquor stores join churches to save dry counties | url = https://www.bloomberg.com/news/2014-10-27/arkansas-liquor-stores-join-churches-to-save-dry-counties.html | work = ] | publisher = ] | date = October 27, 2014 | url-status = dead | archive-url = https://web.archive.org/web/20150114075546/http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2014-10-27/arkansas-liquor-stores-join-churches-to-save-dry-counties.html | archive-date = January 14, 2015 }}</ref> | |||
2) Willie Morris, the editor of Harper's Magazine in the 1960s, published a memoir of growing up in Mississippi. He wrote: | |||
{{Blockquote | |||
|text= | |||
⚫ | Mississippi was a dry state, one of the last in America, but its dryness was merely academic, a gesture to the preachers and the churches. My father would say that the only difference between Mississippi and its neighbor Tennessee, which was wet, was that in Tennessee a man could not buy liquor on Sunday. The Mississippi bootleggers, who theoretically operated "grocery stores," with ten or twelve cans of sardines and a few boxes of crackers for sale, stayed open at all hours, and would sell to anyone regardless of age or race. My father could work himself into a mild frenzy talking about this state of affairs; Mississippi, he would say, was the poorest state in the union, and in some ways the worst, and here it was depriving itself of tax money because the people who listened to the preachers did not have the common sense to understand what was going on. | ||
⚫ | Every so often there would be a vote to determine whether liquor should be made legal. Then, for weeks before, the town would be filled with feverish campaign activity. People would quote the old saying, "As long as the people of Mississippi can stagger to the polls, they'll vote dry." A handful of people would come right out and say that liquor should be made legal, so that the bootleggers and the sheriffs would not be able to make all the money, and because the state legislature's "black-market tax" on whiskey, a pittance of a tax that actually contradicted the state constitution, was a shameful deceit. But these voices were few, and most of the campaigning was done by the preachers and the church groups. In their sermons the preachers would talk about the dangers of alcoholism, and the shame of all the liquor ads along the highways in Tennessee and Louisiana, and the temptations this offered the young people. Two or three weeks before the vote, the churches would hand out bumper stickers to put on cars; in big red letters they said, "For the sake of my family, vote dry." An older boy, the son of one of the most prosperous bootleggers, drove around town in a new Buick, with three of those bumper stickers plastered on front and back: "For the sake of my family, vote dry." | ||
|author=Morris, Willie | |||
|source=North Toward Home (1967)}} | |||
==Other applications== | |||
Bootleggers and Baptists has been invoked to explain nearly every political alliance for regulation in the United States in the last 30 years including the ],<ref>{{cite book | last1 = Ackerman | first1 = Bruce | last2 = Hassler | first2 = William T. | title = Clean coal/dirty air: or how the Clean air act became a multibillion-dollar bail-out for high-sulfur coal producers and what should be done about it | publisher = Yale University Press | location = New Haven, Connecticut | year = 1981 | isbn = 9780300026436 | url-access = registration | url = https://archive.org/details/cleancoaldirtyai00acke }}</ref> interstate trucking,<ref>{{cite journal | last = Benson | first = Bruce L. | title = Regulatory disequilibrium and inefficiency: the case of interstate trucking | journal = ] | volume = 15 | issue = 2 | pages = 229–255 | doi = 10.1023/A:1015722906781 | date = June 2002 | s2cid = 37950155 }}</ref> state liquor stores,<ref>{{cite journal | last1 = Benson | first1 = Bruce L. | last2 = Rasmussen | first2 = David W. | last3 = Zimmerman | first3 = Paul R. | title = Implicit taxes collected by state liquor monopolies | journal = ] | volume = 115 | issue = 3–4 | pages = 313–331 | doi = 10.1023/A:1024240400780 | jstor = 30025994 | date = June 2003 | s2cid = 154533733 }}</ref> the ],<ref>{{cite journal | last1 = High | first1 = Jack | last2 = Coppin | first2 = Clayton A. | title = Wiley and the whiskey industry: strategic behavior in the passage of the Pure Food Act | journal = ] | volume = 62 | issue = 2 | pages = 286–309 | doi = 10.2307/3116002 | date = Summer 1988 | jstor = 3116002 | s2cid = 155468515 }}</ref> environmental policy,<ref>{{cite journal | last = Lyons | first = Michael | title = Political self-interest and U.S. environmental policy | journal = ] | volume = 39 | issue = 2 | pages = 271–294 | ssrn = 171397 | date = Spring 1999 | url = http://lawschool.unm.edu/NRJ/volumes/39/v39_no2.php }} </ref> regulation of ],<ref>{{cite book | last = Meins | first = Erika | title = Politics and public outrage: explaining transatlantic and intra-European diversity of regulations on food irradiation and genetically modified food | publisher = Lit Transaction Publishers | location = Münster Piscataway, New Jersey | year = 2003 | isbn = 9783825867676 }}</ref> the ],<ref>{{cite journal | last = Reynolds | first = Alan | title = The politics of NAFTA | journal = ] | volume = 45 | issue = 20 | pages = 42–44 | date = 18 October 1993 }}</ref> environmental politics,<ref>{{cite book | last = Rosenbaum | first = Walter A. | title = Environmental politics and policy | publisher = CQ-Roll Call Group Books | location = Washington, D.C. | year = 1995 | edition = 3rd | isbn = 9780871878489 }}</ref> gambling legislation,<ref>{{cite news | last = Schmidt | first = Susan | title = Casino bid prompted high-stakes lobbying | url = https://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/articles/A30274-2005Mar12.html | newspaper = ] | publisher = ] | date = 13 March 2005 }}</ref> blood donation,<ref>{{cite book | last1 = Thomas | first1 = Diana W. | last2 = Thomas | first2 = Michael D. | title = Efficient regulation? The case of the market for blood | location = Logan | publisher = Department of Economics and Finance, Utah State University | year = 2010 }} Working paper. | |||
:''See also'': {{cite journal | last1 = Thomas | first1 = Diana W. | last2 = Simmons | first2 = Randy T. | last3 = Yonk | first3 = Ryan M. | title = Bootleggers, Baptists, and political entrepreneurs: key players in the rational game and morality play of regulatory politics | journal = ] | volume = 15 | issue = 3 | pages = 367–381 | date = Winter 2011 | url = http://www.independent.org/publications/tir/article.asp?a=816 }} </ref> wine regulation,<ref>{{cite journal | last1 = Wiseman | first1 = Alan. E. | last2 = Ellig | first2 = Jerry | title = The politics of wine: trade barriers, interest groups, and the commerce class | journal = ] | volume = 69 | issue = 3 | pages = 859–875 | doi = 10.1111/j.1468-2508.2007.00580.x | jstor = 10.1111 | date = August 2007 | citeseerx = 10.1.1.517.6921 | s2cid = 53128902 }}</ref> and the ].<ref>{{cite journal | last1 = Yandle | first1 = Bruce | last2 = Rotondi | first2 = Joseph A. | last3 = Morriss | first3 = Andrew P. | last4 = Dorchak | first4 = Andrew | author-link = Bruce Yandle | title = Bootleggers, Baptists & Televangelists: regulating tobacco by litigation | journal = ] | volume = 82 | pages = 1225–1284 | ssrn = 1010695 | date = 2007 | url = http://law.bepress.com/uiuclwps/art82/ }} </ref> | |||
Legislation and treaties to reduce ] often command support of both polluting countries and environmentalists. Yandle and Buck argue that a similar phenomenon took place in the battle over the Kyoto Protocol, where the "Baptist" environmental groups provided moral support while "bootlegger" corporations and nations worked in the background to seek economic advantages over their rivals.<ref name=GW /> | |||
== See also == | |||
{{Portal|Liquor|Law|Politics}} | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
* ] | |||
{{Clear}} | |||
== References == | |||
⚫ | {{Reflist|30em}} | ||
==External links== | ==External links== | ||
* {{cite journal | last = Yandle | first = Bruce | author-link = Bruce Yandle | title = Bootleggers and Baptists in retrospect | journal = ] | volume = 22 | issue = 3 | pages = 5–7 | date = October 1999 | url = http://www.cato.org/regulation/archives }} | |||
* | |||
* | * Yandle discusses the story with Russ Roberts at EconTalk. | ||
{{DEFAULTSORT:Bootleggers And Baptists}} | |||
] | |||
] | ] | ||
] |
Latest revision as of 04:29, 20 August 2024
Economic conceptBootleggers and Baptists is a concept put forth by regulatory economist Bruce Yandle, derived from the observation that regulations are supported both by groups that want the ostensible purpose of the regulation, and by groups that profit from undermining that purpose.
For much of the 20th century, Baptists and other evangelical Christians were prominent in political activism for Sunday closing laws restricting the sale of alcohol. Bootleggers sold alcohol illegally, and got more business if legal sales were restricted. Yandle wrote that "Such a coalition makes it easier for politicians to favor both groups. ... the Baptists lower the costs of favor-seeking for the bootleggers, because politicians can pose as being motivated purely by the public interest even while they promote the interests of well-funded businesses. ... take the moral high ground, while the bootleggers persuade the politicians quietly, behind closed doors."
Economic theory
The mainstream economic theory of regulation treats politicians and administrators as brokers among interest groups. Bootleggers and Baptists is a specific idea in the subfield of regulatory economics that attempts to predict which interest groups will succeed in obtaining rules they favor. It holds that coalitions of opposing interests that can agree on a common rule will be more successful than one-sided groups.
Baptists do not merely agitate for legislation, they help monitor and enforce it (a law against Sunday alcohol sales without significant public support would likely be ignored, or be evaded through bribery of enforcement officers). Thus bootleggers and Baptists is not just an academic restatement of the common political accusation that shadowy for-profit interests are hiding behind public-interest groups to fund deceptive legislation. It is a rational theory to explain relative success among types of coalitions.
Another part of the theory is that bootleggers and Baptists produce suboptimal legislation. Although both groups are satisfied with the outcome, broader society would be better off either with no legislation or different legislation. For example, a surtax on Sunday alcohol sales could reduce Sunday alcohol consumption as much as making it illegal. Instead of enriching bootleggers and imposing policing costs, the surtax could raise money to be spent on, say, property tax exemptions for churches and alcoholism treatment programs. Moreover, such a program could be balanced to reflect the religious beliefs and drinking habits of everyone, not just certain groups. From the religious point of the view, the bootleggers have not been cut out of the deal, the government has become the bootlegger.
Although the bootleggers and Baptists story has become a standard idea in regulatory economics, it has not been systematically validated as an empirical proposition. It is a catch-phrase useful in analyzing regulatory coalitions rather than an accepted principle of economics.
Literal examples
1) In 2015, liquor stores in the "wet counties" of Arkansas allied with local religious leaders to oppose statewide legalization of alcohol sales. Where the religious groups were opposed on moral grounds, the liquor stores were concerned over the potential loss of customers if rival stores were permitted to open in the "dry" counties of the state.
2) Willie Morris, the editor of Harper's Magazine in the 1960s, published a memoir of growing up in Mississippi. He wrote:
Mississippi was a dry state, one of the last in America, but its dryness was merely academic, a gesture to the preachers and the churches. My father would say that the only difference between Mississippi and its neighbor Tennessee, which was wet, was that in Tennessee a man could not buy liquor on Sunday. The Mississippi bootleggers, who theoretically operated "grocery stores," with ten or twelve cans of sardines and a few boxes of crackers for sale, stayed open at all hours, and would sell to anyone regardless of age or race. My father could work himself into a mild frenzy talking about this state of affairs; Mississippi, he would say, was the poorest state in the union, and in some ways the worst, and here it was depriving itself of tax money because the people who listened to the preachers did not have the common sense to understand what was going on. Every so often there would be a vote to determine whether liquor should be made legal. Then, for weeks before, the town would be filled with feverish campaign activity. People would quote the old saying, "As long as the people of Mississippi can stagger to the polls, they'll vote dry." A handful of people would come right out and say that liquor should be made legal, so that the bootleggers and the sheriffs would not be able to make all the money, and because the state legislature's "black-market tax" on whiskey, a pittance of a tax that actually contradicted the state constitution, was a shameful deceit. But these voices were few, and most of the campaigning was done by the preachers and the church groups. In their sermons the preachers would talk about the dangers of alcoholism, and the shame of all the liquor ads along the highways in Tennessee and Louisiana, and the temptations this offered the young people. Two or three weeks before the vote, the churches would hand out bumper stickers to put on cars; in big red letters they said, "For the sake of my family, vote dry." An older boy, the son of one of the most prosperous bootleggers, drove around town in a new Buick, with three of those bumper stickers plastered on front and back: "For the sake of my family, vote dry."
— Morris, Willie, North Toward Home (1967)
Other applications
Bootleggers and Baptists has been invoked to explain nearly every political alliance for regulation in the United States in the last 30 years including the Clean Air Act, interstate trucking, state liquor stores, the Pure Food and Drug Act, environmental policy, regulation of genetically modified organisms, the North American Free Trade Agreement, environmental politics, gambling legislation, blood donation, wine regulation, and the tobacco settlement.
Legislation and treaties to reduce global warming often command support of both polluting countries and environmentalists. Yandle and Buck argue that a similar phenomenon took place in the battle over the Kyoto Protocol, where the "Baptist" environmental groups provided moral support while "bootlegger" corporations and nations worked in the background to seek economic advantages over their rivals.
See also
References
- ^ Yandle, Bruce (May–June 1983). "Bootleggers and Baptists: the education of a regulatory economist". Regulation. 7 (3): 12–16. Pdf. Archived 2016-04-13 at the Wayback Machine
- See also: Yandle, Bruce (October 1999). "Bootleggers and Baptists in retrospect". Regulation. 22 (3): 5–7. Pdf. Archived 2012-10-03 at the Wayback Machine and Bootleggers and Baptists: How Economic Forces and Moral Persuasion Interact to Shape Regulatory Politics. Cato Institute. 2014. ISBN 978-1939709363.
- McChesney, Fred S. (1997). Money for nothing: politicians, rent extraction, and political extortion. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press. ISBN 9780674583306.
- ^ Yandle, Bruce; Buck, Stuart (14 August 2001). "Bruce, bootleggers, Baptists, and the global warming battle". SSRN. doi:10.2139/ssrn.279914. SSRN 279914.
- Baldwin, Robert; Cave, Martin; Lodge, Martin (2010). The Oxford handbook of regulation. Oxford New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 9780199655885.
- Lasswell, Harold (1950) . Politics: who gets what, when, how?. New York: McGraw-Hill. OCLC 21939663.
- Kahn, Alfred E. (1988). The economics of regulation : principles and institutions. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press. ISBN 9780262610520.
- Bryner, Gary (1987). Bureaucratic discretion: law and policy in federal regulatory agencies. New York: Pergamon Press. ISBN 9780080344935.
- Tullock, Gordon (1980), "Rent seeking as a negative sum game", in Buchanan, James M.; Tollison, Robert D.; Tullock, Gordon (eds.), Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society, College Station: Texas A & M University, pp. 16–38, ISBN 9780890960905.
- Wagner, Richard E. (December 1966). "Reviewed work: The Logic of Collective Action by Mancur Olson, Jr". Papers on Non-Market Decision Making. 1: 161–170. JSTOR 25122288.
- Buchanan, James M. (1980), "Rent seeking and profit seeking", in Buchanan, James M.; Tollison, Robert D.; Tullock, Gordon (eds.), Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society, College Station: Texas A & M University, pp. 3–15, ISBN 9780890960905.
- Sutter, Daniel (June 2002). "The democratic efficiency debate and definitions of political equilibrium". The Review of Austrian Economics. 15 (2): 199–209. doi:10.1023/A:1015766621802. S2CID 73557743.
- Schneider, Mark; Teske, Paul (September 1992). "Toward a theory of the political entrepreneur: evidence from local government". American Political Science Review. 86 (3): 737–747. doi:10.2307/1964135. JSTOR 1964135. S2CID 155041917.
- Breyer, Stephen (1982). Regulation and its reform. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press. ISBN 9780674753761.
- Deprez, Esmé E.; Hogue, Millie (October 27, 2014). "Arkansas liquor stores join churches to save dry counties". Bloomberg Politics. Bloomberg News. Archived from the original on January 14, 2015.
- Ackerman, Bruce; Hassler, William T. (1981). Clean coal/dirty air: or how the Clean air act became a multibillion-dollar bail-out for high-sulfur coal producers and what should be done about it. New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press. ISBN 9780300026436.
- Benson, Bruce L. (June 2002). "Regulatory disequilibrium and inefficiency: the case of interstate trucking". The Review of Austrian Economics. 15 (2): 229–255. doi:10.1023/A:1015722906781. S2CID 37950155.
- Benson, Bruce L.; Rasmussen, David W.; Zimmerman, Paul R. (June 2003). "Implicit taxes collected by state liquor monopolies". Public Choice. 115 (3–4): 313–331. doi:10.1023/A:1024240400780. JSTOR 30025994. S2CID 154533733.
- High, Jack; Coppin, Clayton A. (Summer 1988). "Wiley and the whiskey industry: strategic behavior in the passage of the Pure Food Act". Business History Review. 62 (2): 286–309. doi:10.2307/3116002. JSTOR 3116002. S2CID 155468515.
- Lyons, Michael (Spring 1999). "Political self-interest and U.S. environmental policy". Natural Resources Journal. 39 (2): 271–294. SSRN 171397. Pdf.
- Meins, Erika (2003). Politics and public outrage: explaining transatlantic and intra-European diversity of regulations on food irradiation and genetically modified food. Münster Piscataway, New Jersey: Lit Transaction Publishers. ISBN 9783825867676.
- Reynolds, Alan (18 October 1993). "The politics of NAFTA". National Review. 45 (20): 42–44.
- Rosenbaum, Walter A. (1995). Environmental politics and policy (3rd ed.). Washington, D.C.: CQ-Roll Call Group Books. ISBN 9780871878489.
- Schmidt, Susan (13 March 2005). "Casino bid prompted high-stakes lobbying". The Washington Post. Nash Holdings LLC.
- Thomas, Diana W.; Thomas, Michael D. (2010). Efficient regulation? The case of the market for blood. Logan: Department of Economics and Finance, Utah State University. Working paper.
- See also: Thomas, Diana W.; Simmons, Randy T.; Yonk, Ryan M. (Winter 2011). "Bootleggers, Baptists, and political entrepreneurs: key players in the rational game and morality play of regulatory politics". The Independent Review. 15 (3): 367–381. Pdf.
- Wiseman, Alan. E.; Ellig, Jerry (August 2007). "The politics of wine: trade barriers, interest groups, and the commerce class". The Journal of Politics. 69 (3): 859–875. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.517.6921. doi:10.1111/j.1468-2508.2007.00580.x. JSTOR 10.1111. S2CID 53128902.
- Yandle, Bruce; Rotondi, Joseph A.; Morriss, Andrew P.; Dorchak, Andrew (2007). "Bootleggers, Baptists & Televangelists: regulating tobacco by litigation". University of Illinois College of Law: Law and Economics Working Papers. 82: 1225–1284. SSRN 1010695. Pdf.
External links
- Yandle, Bruce (October 1999). "Bootleggers and Baptists in retrospect". Regulation. 22 (3): 5–7. Pdf.
- Podcast. Yandle discusses the story with Russ Roberts at EconTalk.