Misplaced Pages

Fractional-reserve banking: Difference between revisions

Article snapshot taken from Wikipedia with creative commons attribution-sharealike license. Give it a read and then ask your questions in the chat. We can research this topic together.
Browse history interactively← Previous editNext edit →Content deleted Content addedVisualWikitext
Revision as of 17:15, 26 December 2007 editGregalton (talk | contribs)Extended confirmed users5,226 edits Libertarian viewpoint: Delete section - please use talk page before restoring; there is no reason given to have a separate section on this← Previous edit Revision as of 17:28, 26 December 2007 edit undoN0 D1C4 (talk | contribs)101 editsm Reverted 1 edit by Gregalton; Please do not memory hole critics, get consensus first. (TW)Next edit →
Line 924: Line 924:
# Central bank support and government protection of creditors creates moral hazard and socializes ]. # Central bank support and government protection of creditors creates moral hazard and socializes ].


=== Libertarian viewpoint ===


These links discuss "fractional-reserve banking" from the Libertarian perspective. ] is critical of the practice and proposes alternative systems.

* Murray N. Rothbard uses the term "fractional-reserve banking" in reference to both commercial and central bank practices. He characterizes the customary modern-day practices with terms such as ''counterfeit,'' ''swindle,'' and "creating money out of thin air," and asserts that "the general public, not inducted into the mysteries of banking, still persists in thinking that their money remains 'in the bank.'"

* , afs video stream from The ]. Good presentation of the Misesean case against the ].

* The Misplaced Pages entry ] gives an overview of the Austrian School's views on the relationship between Fractional Reserve Banking, Fiat Money, Credit Policies and the Business Cycle.

* An extensively researched, free, 67-page scientific paper with a 69 item bibliography with notes/comments on most major references (c. 2002).

* Misplaced Pages entry ] summarizes a widely seen movie documentary on the history of central banking, monetary policy, the "bond system", the Federal Reserve System, and fractional-reserve banking in the United States.

* is a critical analysis of Rothbard's views by Gene Callahan, who finds them unconvincing, and asserts that banking practices are compatible with Libertarianism, or could be made so with only minor alterations. He discusses at length (but inconclusively) the question of what depositors actually believe, which he sees as relevant to the charge that fractional-reserve banking is fraudulent or deceptive.


== See also == == See also ==

Revision as of 17:28, 26 December 2007

This article may require cleanup to meet Misplaced Pages's quality standards. No cleanup reason has been specified. Please help improve this article if you can. (December 2007) (Learn how and when to remove this message)
The neutrality of this article is disputed. Relevant discussion may be found on the talk page. Please do not remove this message until conditions to do so are met. (December 2007) (Learn how and when to remove this message)

Fractional-reserve banking refers to the common banking practice of issuing more credit than the bank holds as reserves. Banks in modern economies typically loan their customers many times the sum of the credit reserves than they hold.

The expansion of $1,000 of actual money. $4,000 of virtual money is created through fractional reserve lending at a 20 percent rate.

History

At one time, people deposited gold coins and silver coins at goldsmiths for safe keeping, receiving in turn a note for their deposit. Once these notes became a trusted medium of exchange an early form of paper money was born, in the form of gold certificates and silver certificates.

As the notes were used directly in trade, the goldsmiths noted that people would never redeem all their notes at the same time, and saw the opportunity to issue new bank notes in the form of interest paying loans. These generated income—a process that altered their role from passive guardians of bullion charging fees for safe storage, to interest-paying and earning banks. Fractional-reserve banking was born. When creditors (the owners of the notes) lost faith in the ability of the bank to exchange their notes back into coins, many would try to redeem their notes at the same time. This was called a bank run and many early banks either went into insolvency or refused to pay up.

How it works

How the fractional reserve system can turn $1,000 into $4,570.50

In this example, an initial deposit of $1,000 is loaned out 10 times at a fractional reserve rate of 20%. In an attempt to simplify an explantion of how it works, a different bank is used for each deposit. In the real world, sometimes when a bank gives out a loan, that same money ends up right back in the same bank so it then has more money to loan out.

Table 1: $1,000 of actual money loaned out 10 times at 20 percent rate
Individual Bank amount deposited at bank amount loaned out amount left in bank (reserves)
A $1,000.00 $800.00 $200.00
B $800.00 $640.00 $160.00
C $640.00 $512.00 $128.00
D $512.00 $409.60 $102.40
E $409.60 $327.68 $81.92
F $327.68 $262.14 $65.54
G $262.14 $209.72 $52.43
H $209.72 $167.77 $41.94
I $167.77 $134.22 $33.55
J $134.22 $107.37 $26.84
K $107.37
total reserves:
$892.63
total deposits: total amount loaned out: total reserves + last amount deposited
$4,570.50 $3,570.50 $1,000.00

Notice how no new money was physically created. Only the $1,000 from the initial deposit was used. New money is created virtually through loans. The 2 boxes marked in red show where the original $1,000 is throughout the entire process. The total reserves plus the last deposit will always equal the original amount, which in this case is $1,000. As this process continues, more new money is created.

Also notice how when a loan is paid back, money is erased from existance. This is how the money supply is expanded and contracted through a fractional reserve lending system.

Detailed table of how money is expanded with a 20 percent rate

Table 2: 20 percent fractional reserve rate
Individual Bank amount deposited at individual bank cumulative deposits amount loaned out by individual bank cumulative loans amount left in individual bank (reserves) cumulative reserves
A 1000 1000 800 800 200 200
B 800 1800 640 1440 160 360
C 640 2440 512 1952 128 488
D 512 2952 409.6 2361.6 102.4 590.4
E 409.6 3361.6 327.68 2689.28 81.92 672.32
F 327.68 3689.28 262.14 2951.42 65.54 737.86
G 262.14 3951.42 209.72 3161.14 52.43 790.28
H 209.72 4161.14 167.77 3328.91 41.94 832.23
I 167.77 4328.91 134.22 3463.13 33.55 865.78
J 134.22 4463.13 107.37 3570.5 26.84 892.63
K 107.37 4570.5 85.9 3656.4 21.47 914.1
L 85.9 4656.4 68.72 3725.12 17.18 931.28
M 68.72 4725.12 54.98 3780.1 13.74 945.02
N 54.98 4780.1 43.98 3824.08 11 956.02
O 43.98 4824.08 35.18 3859.26 8.8 964.82
P 35.18 4859.26 28.15 3887.41 7.04 971.85
Q 28.15 4887.41 22.52 3909.93 5.63 977.48
R 22.52 4909.93 18.01 3927.94 4.5 981.99
S 18.01 4927.94 14.41 3942.35 3.6 985.59
T 14.41 4942.35 11.53 3953.88 2.88 988.47
U 11.53 4953.88 9.22 3963.11 2.31 990.78
V 9.22 4963.11 7.38 3970.49 1.84 992.62
W 7.38 4970.49 5.9 3976.39 1.48 994.1
X 5.9 4976.39 4.72 3981.11 1.18 995.28
Y 4.72 4981.11 3.78 3984.89 0.94 996.22
Z 3.78 4984.89 3.02 3987.91 0.76 996.98
A1 3.02 4987.91 2.42 3990.33 0.6 997.58
B1 2.42 4990.33 1.93 3992.26 0.48 998.07
C1 1.93 4992.26 1.55 3993.81 0.39 998.45
D1 1.55 4993.81 1.24 3995.05 0.31 998.76
E1 1.24 4995.05 0.99 3996.04 0.25 999.01
F1 0.99 4996.04 0.79 3996.83 0.2 999.21
G1 0.79 4996.83 0.63 3997.46 0.16 999.37
H1 0.63 4997.46








total reserves:





999.37

total deposits:
total amount loaned out:
total reserves + last amount deposited:

4997.46
3997.46
1000

As one can see from this table, the total deposits approaches $5,000, the total loans approach $4,000, but they don't reach these amounts. These amounts are the limits to how much the money can be expanded with $1,000 of actual money and a 20 percent fractional reserve rate.

More examples

In line 1 of the example shown in Table 3, a bank receives a deposit of 100 credit dollars (Not Real Money) and credits the depositor's interest-bearing account with 100 credit dollars. At this point the bank is maintaining 100% reserves of credit dollars against the interest-bearing account dollars it has issued. If the bank was required to keep 30% of its deposits in reserve it would then be able lend $70. The person who borrows this money would likely spend it and the money will likely end up as someone else's bank deposit. Line 3 shows the bank's balance sheet after the $70 is redeposited. Note that the bank can now lend another $49, because its total deposits have increased. Line 5 shows the bank's balance sheet after that additional $49 is redeposited into the bank. At this point the system has $219, which is more than twice the original $100 deposit. This process of lending and depositing money can repeat many times until reaching a theoretical maximum of $333 (100 divided by the reserve ratio of 30% times the original cash deposit). Even though banks seem to make money by re-lending the same money many times, they also must pay interest on a deposit before they can lend it. Thus, banks can only make money on the difference between the interest rate they charge on the loan and the interest rate they pay to depositors.

Table 3: Private bank T-account
Action Assets Liabilities Reserves
1 Customer A deposits 100 paper dollars None $100 in interest-bearing deposits 100 paper dollars
2 Bank loans $70 to Customer B IOUs worth $70 $100 in interest bearing deposits 30 paper dollars
3 Customer B deposits 70 paper dollars IOUs worth $70 $170 in interest-bearing deposits 100 paper dollars
4 Bank loans $49 to Customer C IOUs worth $119 $170 in interest-bearing deposits 51 paper dollars
5 Customer C deposits 49 paper dollars IOUs worth $119 $219 in interest-bearing deposits 100 paper dollars


An alternative way of describing fractional reserves is to imagine that the entire banking system receives total deposits of $500 credit dollars, which are booked as $500 checking account dollars, of which $400 of said total deposits were lent to borrowers, receiving the borrowers' $400 IOU (promise to pay back) in swap. $100 credit dollars were the seed to $500 paper dollars, $400 of which were "issued" through the process of being lent into existence.

How a bank can lend more than it has

Reserves (silver, gold, and U.S. Bonds in past banking eras and U.S Bonds or Credit in the present banking era) are a special form of money which can be held by the commercial banks either in their vaults or on deposit at the central bank. They are generally described as a "high-powered" form of money and are needed to perform fractional reserve banking. When a bank is in possession of bank reserves this means that it is able to lend more currency to others than it has on deposit.

If we imagine a bank which has $100 in reserves, with a 20% reserve ratio the bank would be able to lend up to $400 without breaching the ratio. Hence, through each round of lending a portion is held in reserve until that portion approaches a limit of Zero and the issued credit lent into existence approaches of a limit of $400. Thus begetting a sum total of credit dollars approaching $500 total dollars (The initial seed currency "high-powered money" plus newly issued bank created credit dollars).

The balance sheet of the bank in this position will show:

Rothbard circa 1955
Assets Liabilities
Cash reserves $100 Deposit receipt $100

The bank is at the limit of the stipulated reserve ratio and we can see this by the following fraction:

Reserves Total Receipts = {\displaystyle {\frac {\text{Reserves}}{\text{Total Receipts}}}=} 100 100 + 400 . {\displaystyle {\frac {100}{100+400}}\,.}

For the bank to lend more money (while still staying within the reserve limits) it will need to wait until some of the loans have been paid back by the customers.

Murray Rothbard in The Mystery of Banking (page 64):

The Rothbard Bank has issued $80,000 of fake warehouse receipts which it lends to Smith, thus increasing the total money supply from $50,000 to $130,000. The money supply has increased by the precise amount of the credit-$80,000-expanded by the fractional reserve bank. One hundred percent reserve banking has been replaced by fractional reserves, the fraction being $50,000 / $130,000 or 5/13.

The form of the money supply in circulation has again shifted, as in the case of 100% reserve banking: A greater proportion of warehouse receipts to gold is now in circulation. But something new has now been added: The total amount of money in circulation has now been increased by the new warehouse receipts issued. Gold coin in the amount of $50,000 formerly in circulation has now been replaced by $130,000 of warehouse receipts.

Issuing more warehouse receipts than there is gold has an inflationary impact on the money supply.

A bank can lend the money immediately

From The Federal Reserve Bank of New York (Reserve Requirements and Money Creation):

If the reserve requirement is 10%, for example, a bank that receives a $100 deposit may lend out $90 of that deposit. If the borrower then writes a check to someone who deposits the $90, the bank receiving that deposit can lend out $81. As the process continues, the banking system can expand the initial deposit of $100 into a maximum of $1,000 of money ($100 + $90 + 81 + $72.90 + ... = $1,000).

Again this process shows that the reserve portions approaches a limit of Zero while the issued bank created credit dollars approaches a limit of $900 dollars. Thus begetting a sum total of credit dollars approaching $1,000 dollars.

The overarching principal of fractional reserve banking rests on the collective agreement within the banking community that it is impossible to distinguish between currency issued by different banks under the umbrella of Federal Reserve Note System. Therefore all Credit-Money issued in this way is generally fungible which means that the any bank is unable to determine if new money taken in on deposit has come from any other bank including its own bank branches or even the same branch. It is for this reason that there is nothing to prevent the customer from depositing the $90 immediately back into the same bank or any bank and the next borrow to borrow $81 and so on until we approach the $900 dollar limit.

In reality it is not necessary for the group of customers to go through all of these steps and they can borrow the full amount (up to $900) immediately. In this instance the $100 of seed currency whether it be a silver certificate as in past banking eras or $100 of bank created credit in the present banking era, does immediately become $100 dollars of reserve currency and must be held in Vault ATM or Till Cash at the bank (or) Vault Cash/Electronic Book Entry/and or in U.S. Treasuries all held on account with that banks local Federal Reserve Bank.

Illustration of a Fractional Reserve Bank

Example 1: Example Bank Limited Balance Sheet as at 30 September 2007
Assets Liabilities
Specie 300 Banknotes issued 1 000
Total Reserves 300 Demand Deposits 9 000
Banknotes issued by other banks 100 Total Demand Liabilities 10 000
Demand deposits with other banks 300 Term Deposits 6000
Marketable Debt Securities 2 000 Bonds issued 2500
Total Liquid Assets 2 700 Total Liabilities 18 500
Net loans and advances 17000 Equity 1 500
Other Assets 300
Total Assets 20 000 Total Liabilities plus Equity 20 000

In this case the reserve ratio is worked out as Total Reserves/Total Demand Liabilities, i.e. 300/10 000, which is 3%. Because the reserve ratio is less than 100%, the bank is said to be engaging in fractional reserve banking.

Avoiding Confusion with Capital Ratio etc.

It is important not to confuse a bank's reserve ratio with its capital ratio, or other financial ratios. The example above shows equity (capital) of 1500 and total assets of 20000, to give a capital ratio of 7.5%. (Note that this figure is not risk weighted.)

It is also important to note that the term 'reserves' in the reserve ratio generally does not include all liquid assets, for example the above example shows a total of 2700 in liquid assets, including 2400 in assets that the bank could relatively easily and reliably redeem or sell to replenish its stock of reserves. Thus while the bank's reserve ratio is 3% its liquid assets to demand debt ratio is 27%.

Liquidity Management For a Fractional Reserve Bank

To avoid defaulting on its obligations, the bank must maintain a reserve ratio greater than zero. In practice this means that the bank sets a reserve ratio target and responds when the actual ratio falls below the target by:

  1. Selling or redeeming other assets,
  2. Restricting investment in new loans,
  3. Borrowing funds (whether repayable on demand or at a fixed maturity), or
  4. issuing additional capital.

Because different funding options have different costs, and differ in reliability, banks maintain a stock of low cost and reliable sources of liquidity such as:

  1. Demand deposits with other banks
  2. High quality marketable debt securities
  3. Committed lines of credit with other banks

As with reserves, other sources of liquidity are managed with targets.

The ability of the bank to borrow money reliably and economically is crucial, which is why confidence in the bank's creditworthiness is important to its liquidity. This means that the bank needs to maintain adequate capitalisation and to effectively control its exposures to risk in order to continue its operations. If creditors doubt the bank's assets are worth more than its liabilities, all demand creditors have an incentive to demand payment immediately, a situation known as a run on the bank.

Contemporary bank management methods for liquidity are based on maturity analysis of all the bank's assets and liabilities (off balance sheet exposures may also be included). Assets and liabilities are put into residual contractual maturity buckets such as 'on demand', 'less than 1 month', '2-3 months' etc. These residual contractual maturities may be adjusted to to account for expected counter party behaviour such as early loan repayments due to borrowers refinancing and expected renewals of term deposits to give forecast cash flows. This analysis highlights any large future net outflows of cash and enables the bank to respond before they occur. Scenario analysis may also be conducted, depicting scenarios including stress scenarios such as a bank-specific crisis.

Real Example of a Fractional Reserve Bank Balance Sheet and Financial Ratios

An example of fractional reserve banking, and the calculation of the reserve ratio is shown in the balance sheet below:

Example 2: ANZ National Bank Limited Balance Sheet as at 30 September 2007
Assets NZ$m Liabilities NZ$m
Cash 201 Demand Deposits 25482
Balance with Central Bank 2809 Term Deposits and other borrowings 35231
Other Liquid Assets 1797 Due to Other Financial Institutions 3170
Due from other Financial Institutions 3563 Derivative financial instruments 4924
Trading Securities 1887 Payables and other liabilities 1351
Derivative financial instruments 4771 Provisions 165
Available for sale assets 48 Bonds and Notes 14607
Net loans and advances 87878 Related Party Funding 2775
Shares in controlled entities 206 Loan Capital 2062
Current Tax Assets 112 Total Liabilities 99084
Other assets 1045 Share Capital 5943
Deferred Tax Assets 11 Reserves 83
Premises and Equipment 232 Retained profits 2667
Goodwill and other intangibles 3297 Total Equity 8703
Total Assets 107787 Total Liabilities plus Net Worth 107787

In this example the (legal tender) cash held by the bank is $201m and the demand liabilities of the bank are $25482m, for a (legal tender) cash reserve ratio of 0.79%.

Other Financial ratios

The key financial ratio used to analyse fractional-reserve banks is the cash reserve ratio, which is the ratio of cash reserves to demand deposits and notes. However, other important financial ratios are also used to analyse the bank's liquidity, financial strength, profitability etc.

For example the ANZ National Bank Limited balance sheet above gives the following financial ratios:

  1. The (legal tender) cash reserve ratio is $201m/$25482m, i.e. 0.79%.
  2. The central bank notes/balances reserve ratio is $3010m/$25482m, i.e. 11.81%.
  3. The liquid assets reserve ratio is ($201m+$2809m+$1797m)/$25482m, i.e. 18.86%.
  4. The equity capital ratio is $8703m/107787m, i.e. 8.07%.
  5. The tangible equity ratio is ($8703m-$3227m)/10787m, i.e. 5.08%
  6. The total capital ratio is ($8703m+$2062m)/$10787m, i.e. 9.98%.

Clearly, then, it is very important how the term 'reserves' is defined for calculating the reserve ratio, and different definitions give different results. Other important financial ratios may require analysis of disclosures in other parts of the bank's financial statements. In particular, for liquidity risk, disclosures are incorporated into a note to the financial statements that provides maturity analysis of the bank's assets and liabilities and an explanation of how the bank manages its liquidity.

How the Example Bank Manages its Liquidity

The ANZ National Bank Limited explains its methods as:

Liquidity risk is the risk that the Banking Group will encounter difficulties in meeting commitments associated with its financial liabilities, e.g. overnight deposits, current accounts, and maturing deposits; and future commitments e.g. loan draw-downs and guarantees. The Banking Group manages its exposure to liquidity risk by maintaining sufficient liquid funds to meet its commitments based on historical and forecast cash flow requirements.

The following maturity analysis of assets and liabilities has been prepared on the basis of the remaining period to contractual maturity as at the balance date. The majority of longer term loans and advances are housing loans, which are likely to be repaid earlier than their contractual terms. Deposits include substantial customer deposits that are repayable on demand. However, historical experience has shown such balances provide a stable source of long term funding for the Banking Group. When managing liquidity risks, the Banking Group adjusts this contractual profile for expected customer behaviour.

Example 2: ANZ National Bank Limited Maturity Analysis of Assets and Liabilities as at 30 September 2007
Total carrying value Less than 3 months 3-12 months 1-5 years Beyond 5 years No Specified Maturity
Assets
Liquid Assets 4807 4807
Due from other financial institutions 3563 2650 440 187 286
Derivative Financial Instruments 4711 4711
Assets available for sale 48 33 1 13 1
Net loans and advances 87878 9276 9906 24142 44905
Other Assets 4903 970 179 3754
Total Assets 107787 18394 10922 25013 45343 8115
Liabilities
Due to other financial institutions 3170 2356 405 32 377
Deposits and other borrowings 70030 53059 14726 2245
Derivative financial instruments 4932 4932
Other liabilities 1516 1315 96 32 60 13
Bonds and notes 14607 672 4341 9594
Related party funding 2275 2275
Loan capital 2062 100 1653 309
Total liabilities 99084 60177 19668 13556 746 4937
Net liquidity gap 8703 (41783) (8746) 11457 44597 3178
Net liquidity gap - cumulative 8703 (41783) (50529) (39072) 5525 8703

Convertibility

Typically, privately-issued checking account dollars are convertible into paper dollars on demand. But paper dollars issued by the central bank are no longer convertible into silver (or gold, as the case may be). The Federal Reserve Note is thus physically inconvertible, although it remains financially convertible, in the sense that the central bank stands ready to use its bonds to buy paper dollars issued by the commercial banking system. For example, during the Christmas shopping season, when the demand for cash is high, the Federal Reserve will normally swap about 10 billion paper dollars for $10 billion in bonds from the commercial banking system. After the shopping season ends, the Federal Reserve will swap $10 billion in bonds for 10 billion paper dollars from the commercial banking system, thus soaking up the now superfluous paper dollars.

Increased money supply and inflation

Main articles: Money supply and Inflation

Since fractional reserve banking involves the issue of money, the link to inflation has been the subject of debates. According to the quantity theory of money, the expansion of the money supply leads to "more money chasing the same amount of goods" and thus to inflation. Some monetarists believe that the exchange rate or purchasing power of the monetary unit is governed by the quantity of money, including demand deposits and notes, and therefore view fractional reserve banking as a cause of inflation. In fact quantity theorists often call the issue of bank-money 'inflation' and consider a falling exchange rate merely a symptom of inflation. Most schools of economics recognize the link between money supply and inflation; many economists, however, consider the issue of money through the banking system as a mechanism of monetary transmission, which a central bank can influence indirectly by raising or lowering interest rates (although banking regulations may also be adjusted to influence the money supply, depending on the circumstances).

Quantity theorists may either be hostile to fractional reserve banking or supportive of minimum reserve ratios and other government controls on the quantity of money created by commercial banks. The process with which commercial banks practice fractional-reserve banking is explained at deposit creation multiplier.

Government regulation

Banking has been subject to generally a greater extent of government regulation and controls than other forms of business, and banking law has in many countries been the subject of extensive political debate.

Government controls and bank regulations related to fractional-reserve banking have generally been to impose restrictive requirements on note issue and deposit taking on the one hand, and to provide relief from bankruptcy and creditor claims, and/or protect creditors with government funds, when banks defaulted on the other hand. Such measures have included:

  1. Minimum required reserve ratios (RRRs)
  2. Minimum capital ratios
  3. Government bond deposit requirements for note issue
  4. 100% Marginal Reserve requirements for note issue, such as the Peels Act 1844 (UK)
  5. Sanction on bank defaults and protection from creditors for many months or even years, and
  6. Central bank support for distressed banks, and government guarantee funds for notes and deposits, both to counter-act bank runs and to protect bank creditors.

Influence of central banks

Central banks are government owned or sponsored banks that issue banknotes and typically receive special privileges in the form of exemption from restrictions or taxes on note issue, or whose banknotes are made legal tender by government fiat (hence the term fiat currency).

Central banks also operate as fractional-reserve banks, and the reserve ratio policies of the central bank influence specie flows and credit conditions, making the control of fractional-reserve banking a political issue, with financial and economic impacts. Also involved with reserve ratios is the interest rate, because the primary method of attracting cash reserves from within a country and from abroad into the central bank, or stemming their outflow, is to offer higher interest rates on deposits (central banks take deposits as well as issue banknotes).

Some political libertarians and some supporters of a gold standard use the term fractional-reserve banking in reference to fractional-reserve banking by central banks in particular, where the nation's central bank holds fractional reserves of gold bullion, specie (gold coin) or other reserves (such as foreign currency). This occurred before the adoption of irredeemable fiat money in most developed countries in 1971 with the collapse of the Bretton Woods system, when the US government defaulted on its gold payment obligations under the agreement. This usage is superficially similar to the standard usage in economics, in that the ability of a country to redeem only part of its currency in gold can be seen as analogous to the ability of a bank to redeem only part of its deposits in cash, but referring to partly-reserved currencies as a form of fractional-reserve banking may create more confusion than it alleviates. Mainstream economists do not generally make this analogy.

Criticisms

This section possibly contains original research. Please improve it by verifying the claims made and adding inline citations. Statements consisting only of original research should be removed. (October 2007) (Learn how and when to remove this message)
Globe icon.The examples and perspective in this article may not represent a worldwide view of the subject. You may improve this article, discuss the issue on the talk page, or create a new article, as appropriate. (Learn how and when to remove this message)

Although fractional-reserve banking is near universal, it is not without criticism. The primary criticisms relate to the financial risk note holders and depositors bear, and the impact bank notes and demand deposits have on the stock of money, and potentially its value (that is, the effect on inflation and the exchange rate). The proposed alternative to fractional reserve banking is full-reserve banking.

Business Cycle

Main articles: Austrian School and Business_cycle § Austrian_School

Fractional Reserve Banking allows an increase in the supply of currency available to make loans to purchase investment capital, without increasing the quantity of investment capital or real savings. The quantity of loans will be higher than the actual supply of saved resources available for investment. Investors will assume that the quantity of loans available represents real savings. This misinformation leads investors to misallocate capital, borrowing and investing too much in long-term projects for which there is insufficient demand and real savings. As investors spend borrowed currency, segments of the economy will boom. Later investors will find the prices of their outputs falling and their costs rising, leading to the failure of new projects and a bust.

Risk

Main article: Full-reserve banking

Fractional-reserve banking allows for the possibility of a bank run in which the demand depositors and note holders collectively attempt to withdraw more money than the bank has in reserves, causing the bank to default. The bank would then be liquidated and the creditors of the bank would suffer a loss if the proceeds from the bank's assets were insufficient to pay its liabilities. Since liquidation may require selling assets quickly, and potentially in large enough quantities to affect the price of those assets, an otherwise solvent bank (whose assets are worth more than its liabilities) may be made insolvent by a bank run. This problem potentially exists for any corporation with debt or liabilities, but is more critical for banks as they rely upon public deposits (which may be redeemable upon demand).

Although an initial analysis of a bank run and default points to the bank's inability to liquidate or sell assets (i.e. because the fraction of assets not held in the form of liquid reserves are held in less liquid investments such as loans), a more full analysis indicates that depositors will cause a bank run only when they have a genuine fear of loss of capital, and that banks with a strong risk adjusted capital ratio should be able to liquidate assets and obtain other sources of finance to avoid default. For this reason fractional-reserve banks have every reason to maintain their liquidity, even at the cost of selling assets at heavy discounts and obtaining finance at high cost, during a bank run (to avoid a total loss for the contributors of the bank's capital, the shareholders).

Responses to the problem of financial risk described above include:

  1. Opponents of fractional reserve banking who insist that notes and demand deposits be 100% reserved;
  2. Proponents of prudential regulation, such as minimum capital ratios, minimum reserve ratios, central bank or other regulatory supervision, and compulsory note and deposit insurance, (see Controls on Fractional-Reserve Banking below);
  3. Proponents of free banking, who believe that banking should be open to free entry and competition, and that the self-interest of debtors, creditors and shareholders should result in effective risk management; and,
  4. Withdrawal restrictions: some bank accounts may place a limit on daily cash withdrawals and may require a notice period for very large withdrawals. Banking laws in some countries may allow restrictions to be placed on withdrawals under certain circumstances, although these restrictions may rarely, if ever, be used.

Incompatible with a gold standard

Main articles: Gold standard, Seigniorage, and Austrian School

Many critics of irredeemable fiat currency see fractional-reserve banking as incompatible with a return of the gold standard, despite the fact that most countries that used a gold standard in the twentieth century had commercial fractional reserve banking. These critics claim that fractional-reserve banking leading to exhaustion of reserves, prompting governments to make the notes of government-favored banks legal tender, even though the issuer is in default. If such defaulted bank notes are made legal tender by government fiat, as they trade at a discount to their face value in terms of gold coin, will be a cheaper way to discharge debts, driving out gold coin. In countries where commercial banks do not issue bank notes, this issue does not exist.

However, other critics of irredeemable fiat currency, from the free banking school, support fractional-reserve banking, and view the threat to the gold standard as originating from central banking and government controls on the formation and winding-up of banks and the business of banking.

Inadequate government regulation

Critics of current bank regulations argue that:

  1. Minimum reserve ratios put reserves beyond reach in a time of need
  2. Minimum capital ratios are poor regulators of financial risk, as they ignore other portfolio risk drivers such as scale and diversification and come at a heavy compliance cost
  3. Government bond deposit schemes distort government bond prices, bank portfolios and finance methods, and create inflexibility
  4. 100% marginal reserve requirements can be met even if the bank has no reserves
  5. Protecting insolvent banks from their creditors creates moral hazard, and increases the losses bad banks make, and is inequitable, and
  6. Central bank support and government protection of creditors creates moral hazard and socializes credit risk.

Libertarian viewpoint

These links discuss "fractional-reserve banking" from the Libertarian perspective. Economic libertarianism is critical of the practice and proposes alternative systems.

  • Fractional-reserve banking Murray N. Rothbard uses the term "fractional-reserve banking" in reference to both commercial and central bank practices. He characterizes the customary modern-day practices with terms such as counterfeit, swindle, and "creating money out of thin air," and asserts that "the general public, not inducted into the mysteries of banking, still persists in thinking that their money remains 'in the bank.'"
  • The Misplaced Pages entry Business Cycle: Austrian School gives an overview of the Austrian School's views on the relationship between Fractional Reserve Banking, Fiat Money, Credit Policies and the Business Cycle.
  • Misplaced Pages entry The Money Masters summarizes a widely seen movie documentary on the history of central banking, monetary policy, the "bond system", the Federal Reserve System, and fractional-reserve banking in the United States.
  • The Libertarian Case Against Fractional-Reserve Banking is a critical analysis of Rothbard's views by Gene Callahan, who finds them unconvincing, and asserts that banking practices are compatible with Libertarianism, or could be made so with only minor alterations. He discusses at length (but inconclusively) the question of what depositors actually believe, which he sees as relevant to the charge that fractional-reserve banking is fraudulent or deceptive.

See also

References

  • Huerta de Soto, J. (2006), Money, Bank Credit and Economic Cycles, Ludwig von Mises Institute
  • Meigs, A.J. (1962), Free reserves and the money supply, Chicago, University of Chicago, 1962.
  • Crick, W.F. (1927), The genesis of bank deposits, Economica, vol 7, 1927, pp 191-202.
  • Philips, C.A. (1921), Bank Credit, New York, Macmillan, chapters 1-4, 1921,
  • Thomson, P. (1956), Variations on a theme by Philips, American Economic Review vol 46, December 1956, pp. 965-970.
  • Parliament of Tasmania, Monetary System, Report of Select Committee, With Minutes of Proceedings, 1935.
  • John F. Kennedy vs The Federal Reserve
  • More John F. Kennedy vs The Federal Reserve

External links

Categories:
Fractional-reserve banking: Difference between revisions Add topic